Catherine was not the only ruler to consider herself, or be considered, “enlightened.”
Beginning in the 1760s, rulers in Russia, Prussia, Austria, Spain, Sweden, and some of
the smaller states in Germany and Italy began programs of reform that were based
in part on the desire to continue concentrating authority in their own hands and expanding
the military might and economic base of their states, but also on a desire to
improve the lives of their subjects. They increasingly regarded these aims as integrally
related.
The reforms of “enlightened” monarchs shaped many realms of life. In government
and administration, they often reorganized bureaucracies in an attempt to
make them more coherent and speed up the implementation of state policy. Many
of them set up an examination system for civil servants, so that at least some state
offi ces were held by men who had obtained them through their merits and abilities
rather than by simply purchasing them. They tried to unify and codify the body of
laws in their dominions and make the judicial process shorter and simpler. The use
of judicial torture was restricted, and cruel methods of execution such as death by
drowning were abolished, though penalties for crimes remained harsh; in fact, those
for property crimes such as theft grew harsher, sometimes involving deportation or
hard labor in a workhouse.
In economics, enlightened rulers developed protectionist policies in regard to imports
and invested in some industries, with an eye to building up the manufacturing
capacity of their own states. They tried to reduce the ability of independent groups
such as guilds to regulate production, or of cities or provinces to charge tolls on trade
within the country. They were very concerned about agriculture, promoting projects
that would increase the amount of land under cultivation or introduce new crops,
such as the potato. They tried to reform the tax structure; in many places this meant
taxing the clergy or taking over church lands. Occasionally they even taxed the nobility,
though this generally happened only as a last resort, not as a matter of policy. They
supported the establishment of schools, especially those that were oriented toward vocational
and technical education, though they also supported elementary schools that
taught basic reading and writing; the fi rst legislation regarding compulsory schooling
in Europe was in Prussia in 1763. Rulers also supported institutions that cared for orphans,
invalids, the elderly, and military veterans, and tried to curtail the harassment of
peasants by their landlords. They generally did not end serfdom as a labor system, but
attempted to limit those aspects that reduced agricultural productivity or made peasants
completely unfi t for military service. In the 1780s Joseph II of Austria-Hungary
did abolish serfdom, though the obligations of the peasants to their landlords – which
were primarily paid in cash by this point, not labor services – were simply transformed
into tax obligations to the state.
State-sponsored schools competed with those of the church, and rulers limited the
independent powers of the church in other ways as well. In Catholic countries, rulers
asserted greater control of church appointments or restricted the special privileges of
the clergy, such as being tried for crimes in separate courts. In Austria, Joseph II dissolved
many of the monasteries, arguing that their residents were idle parasites, and
that their property would be better used to support secular schools and charitable
institutions. In many countries, rulers abolished the Jesuit order. Religious minorities
were accorded at least limited formal toleration, which was even extended to Jews
in some places at the very end of the century. Such measures were often fi nancially
advantageous, as they boosted the economy by encouraging the immigration of skilled
workers. They were also a clear sign that the church was to be simply one institution
among many whose purpose was to support the state, not a separate body with powers
that rivaled those of the ruler.
Late eighteenth-century absolutist rulers were better able to achieve their aims than
those a century earlier, though their plans still far exceeded their abilities to bring them
about. In their reforms, enlightened rulers were motivated by humanitarian concerns
about the welfare of their subjects, but even more by pragmatic considerations about
the strength of the state as a military and economic unit and the preservation of the
political integrity of monarchical absolutism. They did not see these goals as antithetical,
however, but as closely linked, for healthy, prosperous, contented subjects would
work more, have more children, and be able to pay more taxes.