Leviathan portrays the social body as a collection of individuals, but it was also thought
of – and functioned – as a collection of groups. As we saw in chapter 1 , medieval Europeans
had conceptualized society in three basic groups: those who pray (the clergy),
those who fi ght (the nobility), and those who work (everyone else). These groups were
termed “orders” or “Estates,” and many medieval representative assemblies, including
those of France and the Low Countries, were organized into three houses by Estate.
In England, the higher-level clergy joined the nobility in the House of Lords, with
the House of Commons the rough equivalent of the Third Estate elsewhere. Both the
House of Commons and assemblies of the Third Estate primarily represented the interests
of towns, not the majority of the population who were peasants. Only in Sweden
did the peasants have a special fourth house in the national assembly with their
own representatives.
The society of orders was a system of social differentiation based on function – or
at least theoretical function – in society. It worked fairly well in setting out sociolegal
categories for membership in representative bodies, and highlighted the most
important social distinction in both medieval and early modern Europe: that between
noble and commoner. Status as a noble generally brought freedom from direct
taxation and rights of jurisdiction over a piece of property and the people who lived
on it. Even in the Middle Ages, however, and more strikingly by the seventeenth century,
the more fi xed and inherited hierarchy of orders was interwoven with a more
changeable hierarchy based on wealth: what would later come to be termed social
class.
Within each order there were vast differences in status, power, and wealth. The clergy
included prince-bishops who lived in opulent palaces and poor parish priests who
farmed their own fi elds, while the nobility ranged from wealthy counts with vast estates
to poor gentlemen with a single run-down house or knights with no land at all. In
England, distinctions were made between true nobles with heritable titles, represented
in the House of Lords, and gentry, who paid taxes, had no clear set of privileges, and
sent representatives to the House of Commons. Everywhere in Europe the Third Estate
consisted of very diverse individuals, from affl uent merchant-bankers and powerful
judges to poverty-stricken artisans.
Wealth allowed some male commoners to buy or gain noble titles, and female commoners
to marry into noble families, so that these categories were not static; in the
English county of Lancashire between 1600 and 1642, for example, more than one-third
of the gentry families died out, but their numbers were replaced by wealthy socialclimbing
commoners. Monarchs sometimes attempted to restrict entrance into the
nobility to avoid erosion of the tax base, but the temptation to gain cash quickly by
selling titles massively outweighed concerns about long-term revenue streams. The
steady infl ux of newcomers with no military function meant that the old basis for
noble status was increasingly anachronistic, but commoners’ willingness to spend vast
sums of money for a noble title also indicates the continuing privileges and social cachet
of noble rank. The nobility maintained its status in most parts of Europe by taking
in and integrating competing social elites; where wealthy commoners did not bother
acquiring noble titles, such as the Dutch province of Holland, nobles lost their social
and political role.
Wealth and ability also allowed lower-level nobles to climb higher, especially once
monarchs recognized that selling infl ated noble titles was an excellent way to make
money. James I invented the title of “baronet” in 1611, while Spain had fi fty-fi ve titled
nobles in 1520, and nearly ten times that number in 1700. In England, a noble title
brought prestige and certain legal privileges, while in Spain and France it brought freedom
from many taxes, so that the long-term fi nancial implications of such sales for the
royal treasury were signifi cant.
The most common way to gain a noble title was to buy one, but the fastest way to
climb in terms of title, status, and actual power was through gaining royal or princely
favor at court. Courts were cultural, political, and economic centers in which rulers
dispensed favors, offi ces, gifts, and rewards. At Louis XIV’s court at Versailles, the
palace built by the king outside Paris in 1660, nobles vied with each other to carry
out tasks associated with the physical needs of the monarch – bringing in breakfast,
handing napkins, emptying the royal chamber-pot. Though we may view these activities
as demeaning or disgusting, they offered great opportunities for personal
access to the ruler, as did attendance at card-parties, festivities, and entertainments.
French nobles hoping to gain positions moved to Versailles, where they lived in
cramped rooms and ate high-priced cold food bought from vendors, rather than
the more lavish fare they would have been served on their own estates. English and
Austrian nobles were more fortunate, for their rulers continued to live much of the
time in London and Vienna; though nobles had to move to be near them, London
and Vienna offered far more in terms of food, housing, entertainment, and other
amenities than Versailles.
Nobles themselves attended to the needs of the monarch, and they also sought positions
at court for their adolescent children, especially if the young men or women were
physically attractive, intelligent, and talented in music, conversation, or dance. Their
function was largely to serve as decorative objects and high-status servants, and – as
the name lady- or gentleman-in-waiting implies – wait for and wait on the ruler. Success
at court for either an adult or adolescent called for deference, understanding of
ceremony and protocol, discretion, charm, skill, and luck. For women – and for men
with a few monarchs – sexual attraction could also be a powerful tool, with royal mistresses
and male favorites gaining wealth, infl uence, and the power to dispense favors
of their own.
Those who were legally noble generally made up about 1 or 2 percent of the population,
although in Spain and Poland nearly one out of every ten people was technically
noble. In western Europe, nobles owned about one-half to two-thirds of the land, and
in eastern Europe almost all of it. Most nobles did not own very much, however, and
some, such as the impoverished hidalgos of Spain, owned nothing at all, surviving by
payments for mercenary service. Middle-level nobles owned enough land to live comfortably,
and often served as royal judges, commanders in princely armies, or bishops
of smaller bishoprics. At the top were aristocratic families whose vast tracts of land
might provide them with an income of more than a hundred times that of a country
gentleman. The Mendoza family in Spain controlled more than eight hundred villages,
and the Radziwills in Lithuania more than ten thousand.
Inheritance systems shaped the fortunes of noble families over generations, and
they varied throughout Europe. In areas with partible inheritance, which included
parts of France, the Holy Roman Empire, and eastern Europe, land and other property
was divided among sons (and occasionally among all children), diminishing
the family fortune over time. In areas such as England with a tradition of primogeniture,
in which the eldest son inherited all land and the noble title, family wealth
remained more concentrated. The advantages of this system were increasingly clear
to nobles throughout Europe, who pushed for the introduction of primogeniture
or other forms of inheritance, termed strict settlement or entail, that prohibited the
sale or division of family lands. Younger sons generally received stipends of cash, but
were expected to augment this with income from a government offi ce or position in
the church or military. Daughters received dowries, the size of which determined the
young woman’s value in the marriage market; a larger dowry would attract higherstatus
suitors, though social-climbing lower nobles or wealthy urban merchants
might be willing to accept a lower dowry in return for the prestige and access to
power that marrying into a noble family could bring. Daughters who were sole heirs
sometimes inherited the family lands and the right to a title (which they passed to
their husbands) and sometimes not. Gaining this inheritance might involve a protracted
legal battle with uncles or male cousins, however, who argued that gender
should be more important than degree of familial relationship in determining access
to land and position.
In the sixteenth century, nobles and gentry in most of Europe lived in the countryside,
although in northern and central Italy, and southern France and Spain,
they often lived in large households in town, where they might attend the court
of the pope or a ruling duke or count. In the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries,
nobles who could afford it built sumptuous houses in national and regional
capitals, where they sought royal princely patronage and joined in the cultural
activities of the court. They also maintained a steady round of their own social
activities, especially during the “season,” the winter months when life on country
estates would have been uncomfortable and boring. By the eighteenth century,
nobles in western Europe did not have the independent power or vast wealth that
many of their counterparts in eastern Europe did, but they maintained their privileged
position.
Though nobles were increasingly attracted to city life, cities were also where the
hierarchy of orders met the hierarchy of wealth most dramatically. By 1500, and much
earlier in cities in Italy and the Netherlands, a number of urban merchants and bankers
were wealthier than all but the highest level of nobility. Over the next centuries, some
of these men climbed into the nobility through marriage, service to a monarch, or purchasing
a title. More of them heightened social and political distinctions within cities
themselves, often beginning this process by limiting membership in the city councils
they controlled to a small circle of families. They might hope to marry into nobility,
but, as in the German city of Nuremberg, they also prohibited men who married the
daughters of city councilors from joining the council themselves.
The most signifi cant distinction within cities was that between citizen and noncitizen,
as we discussed in chapter 3 . Urban citizenship, described in England as having
the “freedom” of a city, made one a member of a corporate group with legal privileges
and claims on public assistance; it also brought responsibilities, including serving in or
providing troops for the city militia, and paying local taxes. Like noble titles, the status
of citizen was heritable.
Cities also allowed people to purchase citizenship, especially after demographic
catastrophes, and sometimes granted citizenship free of charge for special services
to the city or if applicants for citizenship practiced an occupation deemed desirable,
such as midwifery or surgery. Toward the end of the sixteenth century, though national
capitals continued to expand and fl ourish economically, many smaller cities
stagnated. They responded not by making it easier to immigrate, but by increasing
the standard fees for citizenship to bring in more money, and granting citizenship
free of charge less often. In 1599, for example, the entrance fees for citizenship in
the Swiss city of Basel were raised from 10 gulden to 30, beyond the reach of all but
the wealthiest immigrants. Cities often tolerated outsiders who performed needed
manual labor, and sometimes developed an in-between category for permanent
residents too poor to obtain citizenship, but the native-born still had distinct advantages.
In many cities, sumptuary laws attempted to create easily visible distinctions between
social groups. Nobles were set off by their fi ne silk clothing, university-educated
physicians and lawyers by their velvet- or fur-trimmed robes, servants by their rough
dark clothes and aprons. Individuals tried to evade these laws by wearing the clothing
restricted to the group above them, though there were fi nes prescribed for doing so.
Wearing a disguise or attempting to pass oneself off as someone else was taken much
more seriously, and could warrant the death penalty. Doing so successfully was diffi
cult, for it meant not only acquiring different clothes, but also different speech patterns,
gestures, eating habits, and mannerisms.
As they set themselves off visually with fancier clothing and more elaborate gestures,
middle- and upper-class urban people also attempted to set themselves apart spatially
from the lower classes. Historians have noted an increase in the desire for privacy in the
eighteenth century among middle- and upper-class families, both privacy for the family
as a unit and privacy from others within the household. Thus, for households that
could afford it, servants increasingly had separate quarters, and rooms within houses
were more compartmentalized, with doors that could be closed. Privacy did not extend
to lower-class families in either theory or practice. Poor people in cities lived in very
crowded quarters, often renting a tiny attic or cellar room for an entire family, and