Alexios’ achievement was to rebuild the Byzantine empire. The new and the
traditional were mixed in equal measure. He restored the traditional role
of the emperor in ecclesiastical affairs, but took it further. Caesaropapism
is an apt enough description of his supervision of the church. Politically,
Byzantium was organised on a dynastic rather than a hierarchical basis.
This is perhaps where Alexios was at his most radical because it had farreaching
implications for the organisation of government. It meant that
the emperor shared power with members of an extended family. There
was, on the other hand, no radical restructuring of government. Alexios
was more interested in finding ways of exercising control. His solution was
to create coordinating ministries. The civil service was now subordinated
to the logothete of the sekr¯eta, later known as the grand logothete; the fiscal
services were placed under the control of the grand logariast.
Alexios inherited a bankrupt state. The coinage was miserably debased,
with the gold coinage’s fineness reduced from twenty-four to eight carats.
So desperate was his situation that Alexios had to debase still further, but by
1092 he was able to restore some order to the coinage.He raised the fineness
of the standard gold coinage to around twenty carats and kept the debased
electrum issues, but stabilising them at around six carats. He also kept the
debased silver coinage in the form of a billon coin with a minimal silver
content. He issued a new copper coinage. Alexios’ reform of the coinage
was typical of the measures he took to restore the empire.He imposed order
and stability, but his measures had radical consequences. Michael Hendy
contends that ‘the Alexian coinage reform of 1092 attempted and achieved
nothing less than a complete reconstruction of the coinage system on an
entirely novel basis; . . . only the Diocletianic reform had been on a similar
scale.’30 His innovation was to create a regular coinage based on alloys
rather than pure metal. It is likely that the existence of both an electrum
and a billon coinage, which took the place of the old silver miliar¯esia,
made for a more flexible monetary system. But the greatest service that
Alexios’ coinage reform did was to re-establish clear equivalences between
the different coinages. Their absence had brought chaos to the fiscal system.
In the wake of his reform of the coinage Alexios was able to proceed to a
thoroughgoing reform of the collection of taxes – the so-called nea logarik¯e.
It was essentially an adaptation of the taxation system to the reformed
coinage. It has been estimated that it was done in such a way as to quadruple
the tax rate.
Alexios I Komnenos ended the lax fiscal regime of the eleventh century.
There are no signs that theByzantine economy suffered. It quickly recovered
from a period of dislocation which lasted for approximately twenty years,
from the defeat atManzikert to Alexios’ victory over the Pechenegs in 1091.
The manorialisation of the countryside continued with largely beneficial
results for the peasantry (see above, pp. 584–5). The towns ofGreece and the
southern Balkans prospered. Places such as Corinth, Thebes andHalmyros
(in Thessaly) benefited from a growing Italian presence and there was an
upsurge of local trade around the shores of the Aegean. Constantinople
continued to be the clearing house of the medieval world. The empire was
far from being ‘internally played out’. But there had been a decisive shift in
its centre of gravity from Asia Minor to Greece and the southern Balkans,
which experienced sustained economic growth. It is not clear, however, that
this compensated for the loss of the resources of Anatolia. Its recovery was
always Alexios’ major task.