The debate over the arrangements for recruitment of the army is connected
with the debate over whether the tax system worked in cash or in kind; and
this, in turn, depends on how one believes money circulated. It is unanimously
agreed that circulation dwindled between 650 and 850. However,
recent studies have drawn attention to the vitality of Sicilian gold coinage,
as well as to the role played by the miliar¯esion – the silver coin worth 1
12
of the nomisma, introduced by Leo III in 721. The latter innovation helps
explain the great importance of the fortress of Lulon, located on the border
with the caliphate at the heart of a mining region. The circulation of
copper coins has also been reassessed; this had previously been assumed to
be non-existent, as account had not been taken of the many anonymous
folleis preserved among archaeological finds in Turkish museums, notably
at Ankyra.87
Availability of money was vital for the army, in order to pay the rogai of
the officers and men. The enemy waswell aware of this and the ‘Wells Fargo’
wagon of the rogai, accompanied by the strat¯egos, was a key target for attack.
In 809 the Bulgars seized the rogai of the army on the Strymon, totalling
1,100 pounds of gold, or 79,200 nomismata. Two years later, the Arabs
captured the rogai of the theme of the Armeniakoi, which amounted to
1,300 pounds, or 93,600 nomismata – over three times the annual tribute of
30,000 nomismata paid to the Arabs byNikephoros I in 806.88 It is generally
thought that the roga was paid every four years, though no contemporary
text declares as much.89 The state also needed to issue allowances in kind
to maintain the army on campaign. The system described in the military
Treatise compiled under Constantine VII Porphyrogenitus, but based on
documents of the Isaurian period,90 was probably at least partially in place
from the eighth century.Under this system, the pr¯otonotarios of the theme –
the highest civilian official in the thematic administration, first mentioned
in the ninth century – would supply each military staging-post (apl¯ekton)
with barley for the horses and other necessities; these outgoings would be
recorded in and deducted from the theme’s account in the eidikon, the
central office of the tax administration.91 We can see this supply system
at work in 782 under Irene. According to al-Tabari, she supplied Harun
al-Rashid ‘with guides and markets’ for his journey back from Bithynia to
the caliphate, after he had negotiated a peace treaty in which this featured
as one of the clauses.92
The sources do not really allow us to decide between the two interpretations
of the tax system currently on offer. Those who argue that taxes were
paid in cash do so mainly by reference to the tax on Constantinopolitans for
repairs to the City’s walls; they maintain that the hearth tax, the kapnikon,
as well as the property tax, described by the Farmer’s law in a village context,
were paid in cash from the time of Constantine V.93 This would indeed
appear probable for the kapnikon, which Nikephoros I extended to the
inhabitants of church lands – those belonging to bishoprics, monasteries
and pious foundations – and we even know the rate at which the kapnikon
was paid underMichael II: two miliar¯esia per household.94 But it is harder
to say the same of the property tax.
Two contemporary letters support the idea of a property tax called the
syn¯on¯e, paid in kind: both were written between 820 and 843 by Bishop
Ignatios of Nicaea to the pr¯otonotarios Nicholas, complaining on behalf of
the men of his church. Although these men were theoretically exempted
from the syn¯on¯e, as they were from forced labour and other impositions –
and despite having already sent the grain of the syn¯on¯e to the public granaries
that year – the syn¯on¯e was still being demanded of them, together with an
additional six modioi per male inhabitant. Opinions as to whether the
property tax was paid in cash or kind depend on whether one interprets the
word syn¯on¯e as a property tax or as a requisition; it was originally the Greek
translation of the Latin coemptio, the compulsory, fixed-price sale to the
state of goods needed for the army.95 One might also take into account the
case, under Theodora and Michael III, of the poor who were imprisoned
by the dioik¯et¯es of Prousa for non-payment of taxes; the abbot of Agauroi
gave them 100 nomismata, which had been earmarked to pay the taxes of
his own monastery.96 It is not clear, however, which tax was involved here.
This debate is compounded by another concerning the kommerkiarioi,
whose numerous seals have been found for the period between 650 and 730,
dated by indiction and stamped with the emperor’s effigy. Their legends also
mention warehouses (apoth¯ekai) and the names of several provinces. There
is general agreement that the kommerkiarioi reported to the central office
of finances in Constantinople, the genikon logothesion. Those who believe
taxes were paid in kind argue that the kommerkiarioi were responsible for
depositing the tax proceeds needed for the year’s campaigns in the apoth¯ekai;
and there is undeniably a certain correspondence between the dates and
provinces mentioned on the seals and military expeditions.97 On the other
hand, those who argue that taxes were paid in cash see the kommerkiarioi as
private entrepreneurs who controlled the silk trade for a fixed period in the
provinces where they managed the apoth¯ekai for the state.98 After 730 the
seals of the kommerkiarioi disappear for about a century and are replaced
by impersonal seals ‘of the imperial kommerkia’ from one city or province
or another. This implies reform under Leo III, the exact terms of which are
unknown.However, this might explain the appearance in our sources of the
kommerkion, or indirect tax on transactions. The kommerkion is mentioned
under Constantine VI in connection with the fair at Ephesos, and under
Irene and Nikephoros I in connection with the customs offices on the
Bosporus (Hieron) and the Dardanelles (Abydos).99 At the beginning of
the ninth century the kommerkiarioi reappear in the Balkans and even in
the Danish port of Hedeby, where seals of the kommerkiarios Theodore
have been found.100
This survey of the army and the tax system needed to maintain it, to
ensure the empire’s survival, can only be fragmentary and provisional, and
our knowledge is constantly being expanded with the publication of new
sources, such as seals.However, the most important fact remains the Isaurians’
mobilisation of all the empire’s resources for the army, and the resultant
militarisation of society, which also has the effect of obscuring civilian life.
We know little about the civil administration of the provinces before a
thematic civil administration under the authority of the pr¯otonotarios was
installed at the beginning of the ninth century. All we know is that it
was carried out by chartoularioi and eparchs, who had a role in the tax
system, and by the dioiketai ‘of the provinces’ who were the collectors of
taxes.101
Another consequence of this militarisation was the creation of a military
aristocracy, whose titles were reward for senior command. The Isaurians
surrounded themselves with men who often had their origins outside the
empire: for example under Leo III the patrikiosBeser, or Artabasdos, strat¯egos
of the Anatolikoi and later brother-in-law of the emperor; and under Leo
IV, the five strat¯egoi appointed after the expedition of 778, four of whom
were Armenian. Leo V, himself of Armenian origin, was the son of a patrikios
named Bardas – perhaps the strat¯egos of the Armeniakoi in 771. Leo married
the daughter of the patrikios Arsavir, also an Armenian and probably the
nephew of Bardanes Tourkos (i.e. Khazar), the strat¯egos of the Anatolikoi
who revolted against Nikephoros I in 803. It is also under the Isaurians that
family names first make an appearance – most often as sobriquets applied
to the iconoclasts – and aristocratic families were constituted. Several of the
latter, such as the Kamoulianoi and the Melissenoi, who appeared under
Constantine V, were to have a long history. A good part of the aristocracy
of the ninth century owed its standing to the brilliant military career of an
ancestor in the previous century.