It is difficult to generalise on the notion of an Arabian ‘economy’, since
the internal economic situation in the peninsula varied from place to place
and depended on whether a community was settled or nomadic. As noted
above, the south had a lively village economy based on terraced farming and
irrigation; but even here, production was primarily limited to foodstuffs
and use-value goods. South Arabian spices and incense were much soughtafter
items for centuries, and undoubtedly fortunes were made from trade
in them,57 but overland trade in such goods appears to have collapsed by
the first or second century ad.58
In the rest of the peninsula the economy was far more rudimentary. The
interior of the peninsula consists of various types of steppe lands where
lack of water makes major cultivation unsustainable in most years. Reliable
water supplies come from wells and oasis springs, and it was around these
that Arabia’s towns developed. The date palm dominated agriculture in
many places, and this and other crops were often cultivated in large walled
gardens (h.
aw¯a’i.t) scattered over whatever patches of arable land there were
in or around a settlement. Goats and sheep were kept, and items produced
for sale included hides and leather, wool, cloth, dairy products, raisins,
dates, wine, and utensils and weapons of various kinds. Gold and silver
were mined, but often figured as a replacement for currency rather than
as an export item; perfume was produced, especially in Aden and Najran,
but beyond the Arabian and Syrian markets it could not compete with the
cheaper products of Byzantine centres such as Alexandria.59 Arabian traders
in late antiquity were thus known to their neighbours – in Palestine, for
example – as bearers not of costly luxury items, but rather of animals, wool,
hides, oil and grains.60
Bedouins, on the other hand, were largely herders and pastoralists,
though members of many tribes settled for varying periods of time and
others engaged in opportunistic agriculture – for example by sowing on a
fertile watered plot on their way somewhere else, and then reaping when
they returned. Tenting groups travelled in recognised tribal territories, their
schedules and movements (and willingness to encroach on the lands of
other tribes) largely dictated by the needs of their animals. Those who
lived along the desert fringes tended sheep and goats, as well as the singlehumped
dromedary camel; groups venturing into the depths of the Arabian
steppe lands did best with camels, but on occasion are known to have taken
goats and sheep as well. For barter or sale, nomads could offer such animal
products as hides, leather, wool and dairy products.
The symbiosis between village-dwellers and nomads was important to
the whole economic structure of Arabia. Leather, for example, was an
extremely important product and was the plastic of its day; everything
was made from it, from buckets to items of clothing, and agriculture could
not have been maintained without huge supplies of leather for ropes, irrigation
equipment, harness and so forth. Apart from often quite complex
exchanges of goods and services, bedouins played a major role in economic
development. There is evidence, for example, that parts of different tribes
concluded share-cropping agreements and worked together to promote and
protect agriculture.61 Certain villages also specialised in serving the needs
of nomads, and oases and springs where herds could be watered attracted
settlements that thrived on trade with the nomads. Relations were further
dictated by the need of settled merchants to move their goods through
lands controlled by nomads, and hence to remain on good terms with the
tribes.62
Arabian domestic trade thus consisted of caravans of camels organised
by settled merchants and protected and guided by bedouins who controlled
the lands through which the caravans passed. Seasonal fairs were often held,
especially around religious shrines, and security at such important times
was guaranteed by the declaration of sacred periods during which no raiding
or fighting was to occur.63 The goods being traded were for the most
part not costly items, but rather the basic goods and commodities that
people needed to live. This in turn limited the distance and duration that
the caravans could travel, since the longer the journey, the more expensive
the goods would be at their destination;64 that is, the longer the contemplated
journey was in both distance and time, the more precious the goods
being carried would have to be in order to generate sufficient income to
make the journey economically feasible. The internal trade of Arabia thus
seems to have involved the transport of goods on short or medium-length
journeys, and it is probably this factor that accounts for the proliferation
of market centres. The sources present a picture of lively markets dotting
the steppe landscape of the peninsula; wells, springs and small villages were
all attractive sites for established market activities, though the scale of such
operations was probably small.65 In some cases, commerce was encouraged
by banning private land ownership within the market precinct, thus preventing
dominance by a few successful merchants, and suspending taxes
and fees on traders and visitors.