The ouster of Nikita Khrushchev in October 1964 vividly
demonstrated the challenges that would be encountered
by any Soviet leader sufficiently bold to try to reform the
Soviet system. In democratic countries, pressure on the
government comes from various sources within society at
large—the business community and labor unions, interest
groups, and the general public. In the Soviet Union,
pressure on government and party leaders originated from
sources essentially operating inside the system—from the
government bureaucracy, the party apparatus, the KGB,
and the armed forces.
Leonid Brezhnev, the new party chief, was undoubtedly
aware of these realities of Soviet politics, and his
long tenure in power was marked, above all, by the desire
to avoid changes that might provoke instability, either at
home or abroad. Brezhnev was himself a product of the
Soviet system. He had entered the ranks of the party leadership
under Joseph Stalin, and although he was not a
particularly avid believer in party ideology—indeed, his
years in power gave rise to innumerable stories about his
addiction to “bourgeois pleasures,” including expensive
country houses in the elite Moscow suburb of Zhukovka
and fast cars (many of them gifts from foreign leaders)—
he was no partisan of reform.
Still, Brezhnev sought stability in the domestic arena.
He and his prime minister, Alexei Kosygin, undertook
what might be described as a program of “de-Khrushchevization,”
returning the responsibility for long-term planning
to the central ministries and reuniting the Communist
Party apparatus. Despite some cautious attempts to
stimulate the stagnant farm sector, increasing capital investment
in agriculture and raising food prices to increase
rural income and provide additional incentives to collective
farmers, there was no effort to revise the basic structure
of the collective system. In the industrial sector, the
regime launched a series of reforms designed to give factory
managers (themselves employees of the state) more
responsibility for setting prices, wages, and production
quotas. These “Kosygin reforms” had little effect, however,
because they were stubbornly resisted by the bureaucracy
and were eventually adopted by relatively few
enterprises within the vast state-owned industrial sector.