Finley 1999 remains fundamental. For discussions of the controversies: Austin and Vidal-Naquet 1977, 3-35; P. Cartledge, “The economy (economies) of Ancient Greece,” in Scheidel and von Reden 2002, 11-32; J. Andreau, “Twenty years after Moses I. Finley’s The Ancient Economy,” in Scheidel and von Reden 2002, 33-49. For some critiques of the Finley position: R. Osborne, “Pots, trade and the Archaic Greek economy,” Antiquity 70 (1996), 31-44; Horden and Purcell 2000, 105-8, 143-52. New Institutional Economics: B. W. Frier and D. P. Kehoe, “Law and economic institutions,” in Scheidel, Morris, and Saller 2007, 113-43.
Definitions of peasant society: de Ste Croix 1981, 208-26. Estimates for pottery production in Classical Athens: R. M. Cook, “Die Bedeutung der bemalten Keramik,” Jahrbuch des deutschen archdologischen Instituts 74 (1959), 114-23. Pylos Survey: Davis, J. L., S. E. Alcock, J. Bennet, Y. G. Lolos, and C. W. Shelmerdine, “The Pylos Regional Archaeological Project. Part I: Overview and the archaeological survey,” Hesperia 66 (1997), 391-494. Greek smallholders as peasants: Wood 1988. As yeoman farmers: Hanson 1999, 25-176. For the average size of landholdings: L. Foxhall, “Access to resources in Classical Greece: The egalitarianism of the polis in practice,” in Car-tledge, Cohen, and Foxhall 2002, 209-20. Intensive vs. extensive farming: P. Halstead, “Traditional and ancient rural economy in Mediterranean Europe: plus ca change?” in Scheidel and von Reden 2002, 53-70. Metapontum: Carter 2006; R. Osborne, “Archaic Greece,” in Scheidel, Morris, and Saller 2007, 277-301. Farming strategies and archaeological survey in Attica: S. Forsdyke, “Land, labor and economy in Solo-nian Athens: Breaking the impasse between history and archaeology,” in Blok and Lardinois 2006.
Naucratis: Moller 2000. The economics of desire: L. Foxhall, “Cargoes of the heart’s desire: The character of trade in the archaic Mediterranean world,” in Fisher and van Wees 1998, 295-309. Development of naval architecture: Casson 1994. For a discussion of “transactional orders”: von Reden 1995. For the distinction between exchange and commerce: B. Bravo, “Remarques sur les assises socials, les formes d’organisation et la terminologie du commerce maritime grec a l’epoque archaique,” Dialogues d’Histoire Ancienne 3 (1977), 1-59; P. Cartledge, “Trade and politics revisited: Archaic Greece,” in Garnsey, Hopkins, and Whittaker 1983, 1-15. Estimates of per capita growth: I. Morris, “Economic growth in Ancient Greece,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 160 (2004), 709-42; “Archaeology, standards of living, and Greek economic history,” in Manning and Morris 2005, 91-126; “Early Iron Age Greece,” in Scheidel, Morris, and Saller 2007, 211-41; J. Ober, “Wealthy Hellas,” Transactions of the American Philological Association 140 (2010), 241-86. Marble trade: A. Snodgrass, “Heavy freight in Archaic Greece,” in Garnsey, Hopkins, and Whittaker 1983, 16-26.
For the origins and early function of coinage: J. H. Kroll and N. M. Waggoner, “Dating the earliest coins of Athens, Corinth and Aegina,” American Journal of Archaeology 88 (1984), 325-40; R. W. Wallace, “The origin of electrum coinage,” American Journal of Archaeology 91 (1987), 385-97; S. von Reden, “Money, law and exchange: Coinage in the Greek polis,” Journal of Hellenic Studies 117 (1997), 154-76; “Money in the ancient economy: A survey of recent research,” Klio 84 (2002), 141-74; von Reden 2010; Kurke 1999; H. S. Kim, “Small change and the moneyed economy,” in Car-tledge, Cohen, and Foxhall 2002, 44-51; Schaps 2004. For common coinages: E. Mackil and P. van Alfen, “Cooperative coinage,” in van Alfen 2006, 201-46.